Sie sind hier
E-Book

The Limits of Choice

Saving Decisions and Basic Needs in Developed Countries

AutorSahra Wagenknecht
VerlagCampus Verlag
Erscheinungsjahr2013
Seitenanzahl327 Seiten
ISBN9783593421117
FormatPDF
KopierschutzWasserzeichen/DRM
GerätePC/MAC/eReader/Tablet
Preis34,99 EUR
Wann und warum sparen private Haushalte? Sahra Wagenknecht untersucht in ihrer Dissertation den Zusammenhang von Sparentscheidungen und Grundbedürfnissen in Deutschland und den USA von den 1950er-Jahren bis heute. Ihre zentrale Hypothese lautet, dass der Einkommensanteil der Ausgaben zur Befriedigung von Grundbedürfnissen die entscheidende Erklärungsvariable des individuellen Sparverhaltens darstellt. In Abgrenzung zur Lebenszyklus- bzw. Permanenten Einkommenshypothese (LCPIH) kann Wagenknecht zeigen, dass die individuelle Sparquote entscheidend vom langfristigen Einkommen abhängt. Die Arbeit weist für einen Zeitraum von über 50 Jahren nach, dass sich auch auf volkswirtschaftlicher Ebene die Veränderung der privaten Sparquote durch den 'necessity share' erklären lässt. Das vorgelegte Modell liefert zudem eine Erklärung, weshalb die private Sparquote bei steigender Einkommensungleichheit in Volkswirtschaften mit dereguliertem Kreditmarkt sinkt, während sie bei restriktiven Kreditmärkten steigt.

Sahra Wagenknecht ist promovierte Volkswirtin, Publizistin und Politikerin, seit Oktober 2015 Vorsitzende der Linksfraktion im Deutschen Bundestag. Von 2010 bis 2014 war sie Stellvertretende Parteivorsitzende, von 2004 bis 2009 Abgeordnete im Europäischen Parlament.

Kaufen Sie hier:

Horizontale Tabs

Leseprobe
Introduction

Despite a large amount of detailed economic research studying consump-tion and saving behaviour in several countries, utilizing high-level mathe-matics as well as highly powerful statistical software, the performance of theories attempting to explain the empirical facts still seems to be unsatis-factory. In fact, there is a clear gap between empirically oriented papers about saving on the one hand, and on the other one that part of the literature, which is primarily concerned with estimating the parameters for models of intertemporal utility maximisation that are assumed to guide consumer behaviour. While the issues raised by the latter interest only those believing in the respective models, publications with an empirical focus often reveal interesting relationships of undeniable meaning. Ultimately, these studies mostly note a conflict between their findings and the predictions of mainstream theories.

However, saving is certainly one of the crucial economic variables. Since private-household saving usually accounts for the major part of na-tional saving, it is desirable indeed to clarify what drives an ordinary con-sumer to save or consume his wealth, and to understand how such deci-sions are affected by changes in the economic environment or by politically controlled parameters.

For decades, the Life Cycle/Permanent Income Hypothesis (LCPIH), originally formulated by Friedman (1957) and Modigliani & Brumberg (1954), subsequently highly formalised by making use of dynamic pro-gramming techniques and optimal control theory, has been the central paradigm in economics for studying consumption and saving behaviour. The LCPIH assumes households optimise the utility of consumption in-tertemporally, subject to permanent income or life-time wealth. In this approach, saving is merely a by-product of the optimal consumption path. The exclusive purpose of saving is future consumption since the only trade-off a consumer faces is the trade-off between current and future spending.

The mainstream models are based on the assumption of homothetic preferences and additive intertemporal utility. Preferences are assumed not to be interdependent. The optimal intertemporal consumption path is presumed to be governed by the relationship between the real interest rate, rewarding the accumulation of financial wealth, and a discount factor measuring the degree at which households depreciate future consumption compared to immediate pleasure.

The central prediction of these models under perfect foresight or cer-tainty-equivalent conditions states that consumption does not respond to current changes in income if these have been expected in advance. The effect of an unexpected income shock depends on its impact on perma-nent income. If the income shock is considered to be transitory, consumption remains stable; a transitory income gain will be mainly saved, while a transitory loss will be balanced by dissaving. Only if the consumer expects the shock to be persistent, is consumption adjusted upwards or downwards. The marginal propensity to consume (MPC) out of an increase in current income is consistently assumed to be exactly the same as the MPC out of an increase of equal present value in expected future income.

Vital issues of research within such an approach are to distinguish transitory and permanent income shocks as well as expected and unexpected events. A major focus within empirical work is on estimating the intertemporal elasticity of substitution as the crucial parameter determining the curvature of the intertemporal utility function. In order to refer to aggregate data, the representative agent approach is adopted in most cases, analysing an economy as if it carries out an infinite horizon optimisation problem of a single, immortal, foresighted consumer. This approach requires a number of simplified assumptions about individual preferences.

Yet, the hypothesis of consumers monadically calculating their optimal consumption path far into the future by use of dynamic programming techniques and taking into account the probability distributions of future income streams, life-expectancy and real interest rates, is not just an ap-proach to consumption behaviour. It is one of the cornerstones of modern macroeconomics. As noted by Hahn & Solow (1997), post-Lucas macroeconomic theory stems from two essential commitments: first, a valid macroeconomic model should be the exact aggregation of a microeconomic model; second, the appropriate microeconomic model is based on intertemporal utility maximisation subject to budget constraints and technology only.

In fact, only extremely simplified models at the micro level allow for exact aggregation as the heterogeneity of agents has to be strictly curbed. Except for some recent developments in Dynamic Stochastic General Equilibrium modelling, heterogeneous agents have been entirely excluded in the dominant range of macroeconomic theory. We are not concerned with the consequences for the modelling of firms and competition here. Concerning the theory of the consumer, excluding heterogeneity requires a presumption of homothetic preferences; otherwise distributional parameters influence the aggregate outcome and devaluate the representative agent approach. Interdependencies and strategic interactions also have to be neglected. In fact, the standard LCPIH perfectly fulfils these needs and has therefore been used as an essential module of modern macroeconomic theory.

These models, impressive due to their sophisticated mathematical apparatus impeccably concealing bizarre underlying assumptions, are often the basis for straightforward policy advice. Lucas' critique of the Keynesian consumption function (Lucas, Sargent 1981) was in fact not so much targeted at theory than at policy. Indeed, if people do immediately calculate the permanent income value of a transitory income gain, any political attempt to stimulate demand during an economic downturn by, say, improved social benefits, is simply nonsense. Generally, if forward-looking consumers translate each piece of public debt into an expectation of an additional future tax burden, public deficit spending will only force private households to become particularly eager savers due to adjusted life-time consumption plans. If preferences are, moreover, homothetic, individual saving rates will be completely independent from permanent in-come. Under such conditions, suggesting a policy that favours low-income families in order to encourage effective demand is just an attestation of economic imbecility.

Therefore, the choice of which theory of saving is acceptable as a de-scription of real consumer behaviour and which should better be disre-garded, has far reaching consequences. Ultimately, this should lead to a scrutinising of the reality of the micro foundation of modern macroeco-nomics.

Blick ins Buch
Inhaltsverzeichnis
Contents6
List of Figures12
List of Variables and Abbreviations14
Introduction20
Chapter 1. Stylised Facts of Saving32
Paragraph 1.1 Data Sets and Statistical Issues34
1.1.1 Various Saving Aggregates and Their Relationship34
1.1.2 Macroeconomic Data Sources for the U.S. and Germany35
1.1.3 Measurement Problems—Saving Offshore or Saving Out of Realised Capital Gains37
1.1.4 Statistical Revisions38
1.1.5 Microeconomic Data Sources for the U.S. and Germany39
Paragraph 1.2 The Historic Path of Saving41
1.2.1 General Trends in the OECD41
1.2.2 Saving in the U.S. and its Various Components41
1.2.3 Saving in Germany and its Various Components45
Paragraph 1.3 Stylised Facts at the Macroeconomic Level48
1.3.1 Real Income48
1.3.2 Growth50
1.3.3 Real Interest Rates52
1.3.4 Inflation53
1.3.5 Unemployment and Social Security Standards55
1.3.6 Demographics56
1.3.7 Inequality56
1.3.8 Institutional Environment59
1.3.9 Persistency60
Paragraph 1.4 Stylised Facts at the Microeconomic Level61
1.4.1 Macroeconomic Facts and Microeconomic Distributions61
1.4.2 Saving Rates in Cross-Section62
1.4.3 Current Income, Real and Relative65
1.4.4 Permanent Income73
1.4.5 The Distribution of Financial Wealth75
1.4.6 Growth, Income Fluctuations and the Role of Expectations80
1.4.7 Uncertainty and Precautionary Saving84
1.4.8 Life-Cycle Patterns of Saving86
1.4.9 Saving Motives88
Paragraph 1.5 Summary: Stylised Facts of Saving90
Chapter 2. Do Standard Models of Saving Match the Facts?92
Paragraph 2.1 The Standard LCPIH94
2.1.1 Basic Ideas of the Standard Approach94
2.1.2 The Modigliani-Diagram95
2.1.3 The Perfect Foresight Model in Discrete Time98
2.1.4 The Perfect Foresight Model in Continuous Time102
2.1.5 The Certainty Equivalent Model105
Paragraph 2.2 The Empirical Failure of the Standard Models109
2.2.1 Excess Sensitivity and Excess Smoothness—Ambiguous Results109
2.2.2 MPC and Income Growth—Wrong Predictions110
2.2.3 Incapability to Explain Saving Rate Differentials111
Paragraph 2.3 Refinements: Allowing for Precautionary Saving, Liquidity Constraints and Habit Formation113
2.3.1 Convex Marginal Utility and the Precautionary Motive113
2.3.2 The Technique of Stochastic Dynamic Programming114
2.3.3 The Buffer-Stock Model117
2.3.4 Liquidity Constrained Consumers121
2.3.5 Models Including Habit Formation122
Paragraph 2.4 Do the Elaborated Models Perform Better?126
2.4.1 Gain in Realism at the Cost of Predictive Power126
2.4.2 Remaining Deficiencies127
Paragraph 2.5 The Optimal Consumption Path—General Remarks129
2.5.1 Hidden Assumptions and Fundamental Flaws129
2.5.2 Arguments of the Utility Function—Wealth as an End in Itself130
2.5.3 A Realistic Time-Horizon132
2.5.4 The Representative Consumer133
2.5.5 Per-period Consumption as a Single Entity139
2.5.6 The Elasticity of Intertemporal Substitution142
2.5.7 The Optimising Procedure—Benefits and Costs146
Chapter 3. A New Approach to Saving Behaviour150
Paragraph 3.1 Basic Needs and Saving152
3.1.1 The Relative-Income Hypothesis152
3.1.2 Subsistence Consumption in Developing Countries153
3.1.3 Necessities in Developed Countries157
Paragraph 3.2 Basic Needs in Standard Models160
3.2.1 Introducing Good-specific Subsistence Points into a Standard Dixit-Stiglitz framework160
3.2.2 Intertemporal Optimisation with Moving Subsistence Consumption172
Paragraph 3.3 Modelling Saving Decisions by a Simple Rule of Thumb179
3.3.1 The Necessity Share in Outlay and in Income181
3.3.2 Determinants of Saving under the Proposed Rule of Thumb182
3.3.3 The Aggregated Saving Rate under the Given Rule of Thumb185
3.3.4 Factors Influencing the Propensity to Save and to Dissave192
3.3.5 Summary: Model Predictions193
Chapter 4. The Patterns of Consumption Shares196
Paragraph 4.1 How to Identify Basic Needs?198
4.1.1 Two Approaches to the Historic Path of the Necessity Share198
4.1.2 Basic Expenditure Groups versus Luxury Spending201
Paragraph 4.2 Consumption Patterns at the Macroeconomic Level204
4.2.1 Consumption Shares and Sectoral Prices in Germany204
4.2.2 Consumption Shares and Sectoral Prices in the U.S.207
Paragraph 4.3 Consumption Patterns at the Microeconomic Level211
4.3.1 Methodological Notes211
4.3.2 Food212
4.3.3 Shelter214
4.3.4 Clothing215
4.3.5 Transportation216
4.3.6 Communication218
4.3.7 Furniture and Household Devices218
4.3.8 Health Care219
4.3.9 Entertainment and Recreation220
4.3.10 Education220
4.3.11 Restaurants and Hotels221
Paragraph 4.4 Summary: The Historic Path of the Necessity Share222
4.4.1 What Belongs in the Necessity Basket?222
4.4.2 First Approach to the Necessity Share223
4.4.3 Second Approach to the Necessity Share225
4.4.4 The Individual Necessity Share230
Chapter 5. Does Our Model Match the Facts?234
Paragraph 5.1 Model Predictions and the Stylised Facts of Saving236
Paragraph 5.2 Model Predictions and Empirical Evidence at the Microeconomic Level239
5.2.1 The Necessity Share and German Saving Rates239
5.2.2 Reproducing U.S. Saving Rates of the Mid-20th Century251
Paragraph 5.3 Model Predictions and Empirical Evidence at the Macroeconomic Level257
5.3.1 Preliminary Notes257
5.3.2 Saving Rate and Basic Needs in Germany258
5.3.3 Saving Rate and Basic Needs in the U.S.263
5.3.4 Is Our Model Able to Reproduce the Historic Path?267
Summary304
References310

Weitere E-Books zum Thema: Wirtschaftspolitik - politische Ökonomie

Die Sehnsucht nach einer verlogenen Welt

E-Book Die Sehnsucht nach einer verlogenen Welt
Unsere Angst vor Freiheit, Markt und Eigenverantwortung - Über Gutmenschen und andere Scheinheilige Format: ePUB

Freiheit und Eigenverantwortung statt Ideologie und Bürokratie - Günter Ederer analysiert auf Basis dieser Forderung die existenziellen Probleme unserer Gesellschaft: Bevölkerungsrückgang,…

Die Sehnsucht nach einer verlogenen Welt

E-Book Die Sehnsucht nach einer verlogenen Welt
Unsere Angst vor Freiheit, Markt und Eigenverantwortung - Über Gutmenschen und andere Scheinheilige Format: ePUB

Freiheit und Eigenverantwortung statt Ideologie und Bürokratie - Günter Ederer analysiert auf Basis dieser Forderung die existenziellen Probleme unserer Gesellschaft: Bevölkerungsrückgang,…

Weitere Zeitschriften

Augenblick mal

Augenblick mal

Die Zeitschrift mit den guten Nachrichten "Augenblick mal" ist eine Zeitschrift, die in aktuellen Berichten, Interviews und Reportagen die biblische Botschaft und den christlichen Glauben ...

DSD Der Sicherheitsdienst

DSD Der Sicherheitsdienst

Der "DSD – Der Sicherheitsdienst" ist das Magazin der Sicherheitswirtschaft. Es erscheint viermal jährlich und mit einer Auflage von 11.000 Exemplaren. Der DSD informiert über aktuelle Themen ...

rfe-Elektrohändler

rfe-Elektrohändler

rfe-Elektrohändler ist die Fachzeitschrift für die CE- und Hausgeräte-Branche. Wichtige Themen sind: Aktuelle Entwicklungen in beiden Branchen, Waren- und Verkaufskunde, Reportagen über ...

building & automation

building & automation

Das Fachmagazin building & automation bietet dem Elektrohandwerker und Elektroplaner eine umfassende Übersicht über alle Produktneuheiten aus der Gebäudeautomation, der Installationstechnik, dem ...

elektrobörse handel

elektrobörse handel

elektrobörse handel gibt einen facettenreichen Überblick über den Elektrogerätemarkt: Produktneuheiten und -trends, Branchennachrichten, Interviews, Messeberichte uvm.. In den monatlichen ...